WAGES NOT UNIFORM — NON-COMPETING GROUPS 45
and purchase. Goods do not exchange directly for goods; they
are sold for money and bought for money. The immediate
actuating force is always that of the individual transaction — the
sale of goods to advantage; and this means sale at a profit. How
then can we have any assurance that such conclusions as were
deduced in the preceding chapters concerning the influence of
comparative labor costs have validity for the actual world?
Goods are not bartered — wheat for linen — between countries.
They are sold by individuals for cash. Their sale depends on
prices; and prices are not necessarily, perhaps not usually, deter-
mined by quantities of labor given to producing the goods. How
modify, adapt, reconcile our analysis of international trade to these
plain facts?
Let us revert to the case considered in the preceding chapter.
The figures with which we there began, it will be remembered,
were as follows:
[n the U. S. 10 deys’®
PalleU:. S. &
Germany
Germany
1
Wages
"FR
TOTAL
PropUCE
Y wheat
men
hea,
_o0 linen
Domestic
SuppLy Price
$0.75
$0.75
$1.00
$0.662
The money cost of production of wheat is lower in the United
States than in Germany; that of linen is lower in Germany.
Trade takes place, the United States sending wheat, Germany
sending linen. We still treat the wages outlay — that which the
business world designates as “labor cost” — as if it were the
sole item in supply price; return to capital is left for subsequent
treatment.
Suppose now, that the German wheat laborers get as wages not
$1.00 a day but only $0.663. Suppose them to be, among the
Germans, in a non-competing group, unfavorably situated,
receiving less wages than obtained in other industries, but unable
to betake themselves to the more prosperous group and therefore
permanently in receipt of the lower pay. For the present, accept
differences of this kind, whether in Germany or in the United
States, as simply existent, disregarding the question how they