220 BANKING THEORIES IN UNITED STATES
Lu '
At Ili
pT
needful coin at any moment.” But in practice it is not so. The
causes which alarm one bank alarm the whole. Upon any shock to
confidence, they all call in at once. The stock collaterals are forced
upon the market at the same moment that its ability to take
them is almost destroyed by the total cessation of new loans.” !
The prices of stocks collapse, while merchants are in turn ad-
versely affected by the struggle of brokers for money to avoid
sacrificing their holdings, and by the cessation of bank loans.
The country banks share in the panic and the whole country be-
comes involved. By the operation of these call loans, millions
come suddenly due, and, while they ruin fortunes, they are com-
paratively impotent to strengthen the banks. The calling of
loans cannot increase the total of specie holdings in New York
until it has had time to turn the domestic and foreign exchanges
in favor of that city.?
The call-loan evil was referred to in the next few months by
many others, including the special committee appointed by the
New York Clearing House Association immediately after the
crisis, and a similar committee of the Boston Board of Trade.*
The necessity of maintaining surplus reserves in the New York
depository banks, of discontinuing the practice of paying interest
on deposits, and of eliminating the use of call loans as a secondary
reserve, were matters of commonplace knowledge after 1857.
These criticisms of the specific conditions producing the crisis of
that year, read in the light of what Raguet and others had to say
about the more general nature of the cycle, leave the reader feel-
ing as if he had just turned from the comments of some economist
of 1008 upon the crisis of the preceding year.
t Dwight, “The Financial Revulsion and the New York Banking System,”
Hunt's Merchants’ Magazine (Feb., 1858), xxxviii, 1509.
2 7bid., p- 160.
3 Bankers’ Magazine (April, 1858), xii, 826.
¢ Ibid. (May, 1858), xii, 253.