Non-Statutory Rates to 1601 21]
legal powers of the governing body to impose rates
seem to have been felt till 1549. In that year
assessors were appointed “to assess the burgesses and
inhabitants” to pay “scott and lott for the town debts.
And the bailiffs shall assess tne assessors. Provided
if the order be found contrary to the king’s laws, the
same shall be void.” The doubts must have been set
at rest, as the order was confirmed in the next year,
and the precedent was followed in 1558. In 1592
there was rating for a preachers wages, and in 1597
the burgesses’ salary was rated on the inhabitants.
In those days ratepayers appear to have been expected
not only to pay, but to refrain from grumbling, for we
find that, on 4th December 1573, “ Richard Golty, one
of the burgesses of this town, being allotted to the
sum of 4os, did upon the 10 of October, in the
presence of two persons of credit, say that the scott
and lott rated on him was done against reason, con-
science, charity, and honesty; and being convicted
thereof, he was fined £5, and ordered to pay the
said 40s.”
It would have been a miracle if Tudor legislation
had succeeded in creating a rate altogether unaffected
by the uninterrupted rating practice of three centuries.
To understand our present system, based upon the act
of 1601, it is therefore necessary to know something
about the principles on which these eurly non-statutory
rates were apportioned.
The sewers-rate of Romney Marsh presents no diffi-
culty. It was clearly governed by the principle that
each person whose property was benefited should pay
a proportion governed by the acreage, and afterwards
the value, of that property, in comparison with the